I've Got To Admit It's Getting Better

How the dismal science applies to your life.
Feb. 10 2000 3:30 AM

I've Got To Admit It's Getting Better

And here's a way to measure it.

74000_74648_neubecker_evecon1

Are you better off now than you were four years ago, or 10, or 20? The answer is to be found not in tables of economic statistics but in your kitchen, your family room, and your medicine chest. Would you want to return to a world without microwave ovens, camcorders, automatic coffee makers, VCRs, answering machines, compact discs, and disposable contact lenses? How many people do you know who are living better through Prozac or Viagra, or living longer through cholesterol-reducing drugs such as Pravachol and Lipitor? A decade ago I suffered from incapacitating hay fever; since the drug Flonase became available, I am symptom-free.

Advertisement

You could devote a lifetime to parsing the data on median family income and still completely miss the story of what has happened to the median family's actual lifestyle. Quality-of-life improvements aren't easily expressed in numbers.

But applied economists love numbers, for more than one reason. You need numbers to test the predictions of economic theories. More prosaically, you need numbers to calculate things like cost of living adjustments to Social Security. If the average microwave doubles in price with no change in quality, that's a cost of living increase. If the average microwave doubles in price because people are choosing better microwaves, that's something else.

Here's where Pete Klenow and Mark Bils come in. Klenow is an economist at the University of Chicago. Bils is a colleague of mine at the University of Rochester. The two of them have given a lot of thought to how you'd measure quality changes over time.

Here's their idea: For starters, forget about changes over time, because changes over time are hard to think about. (We'll get back to them later though.) Instead, look at the gap between the rich and the poor. Rich people tend to own more microwaves and they also tend to own better microwaves. More interestingly, there is some statistical regularity to the way the rich divide their wealth between quantity and quality. If you're rich enough to own two microwaves instead of one, they'll cost, on average, about 25 percent more than your poorer neighbor's single unit. The poor man pays $200 for one microwave. The rich man pays $250 apiece for two (presumably better) microwaves.

For other goods, the 25 percent rule doesn't hold, but some other rule holds instead. Take living room tables, for example. If you have two tables and your neighbor has one, yours are probably about twice as expensive as his. If he pays $500 for one table, you'll pay $1,000 apiece for two. So, the 25 percent rule for microwaves gives way to a 100 percent rule for living room tables. Klenow and Bils have estimated the rules for 50 different goods, ranging from vacuum cleaners (a household with twice as many vacuums pays about 22 percent more per vacuum) to trucks (a household with twice as many trucks pays about 140 percent more per truck).

Now, when prices rise over time, it's hard to tell whether you're seeing inflation or a reflection of quality improvement or some combination of both. But when different people pay different prices at the same time, we know inflation has nothing to do with it. So we can infer that when rich people pay more than poor people, they're paying for quality.

In other words, when two microwaves are bought on the same day, the one that costs 25 percent more is presumably 25 percent better. That gives us a measuring rod. We know that when the number of microwaves doubles, their average quality goes up by 25 percent. When the number of living room tables doubles, their average quality goes up by 100 percent, and so on.

74000_74649_neubecker_evecon2

K lenow and Bils assume these ratios haven't changed over the years (and they offer evidence to support that assumption). That's the key to computing quality changes over time.

If in 1980 the average household had, say, .5 microwaves and in 1995 the average household had one, then the twofold increase in quantity should be associated with a 25 percent increase in quality. Or, if in 1980 the average household had .5 microwaves and in 1995 the average household had 1.5, the 200 percent increase in quantity should be associated with a 50 percent (that is, 200 percent times 25 percent) increase in quality.

TODAY IN SLATE

Frame Game

Hard Knocks

I was hit by a teacher in an East Texas public school. It taught me nothing.

Chief Justice John Roberts Says $1,000 Can’t Buy Influence in Congress. Looks Like He’s Wrong.

After This Merger, One Company Could Control One-Third of the Planet's Beer Sales

Hidden Messages in Corporate Logos

If You’re Outraged by the NFL, Follow This Satirical Blowhard on Twitter

Sports Nut

Giving Up on Goodell

How the NFL lost the trust of its most loyal reporters.

How Can We Investigate Potential Dangers of Fracking Without Being Alarmist?

My Year as an Abortion Doula       

  News & Politics
Politics
Sept. 16 2014 11:25 AM The GOP’s Phantom Menace The Republican Party’s new agenda is trying to solve problems that don’t exist.
  Business
Business Insider
Sept. 16 2014 10:17 AM How Jack Ma Founded Alibaba
  Life
Atlas Obscura
Sept. 16 2014 8:00 AM The Wall Street Bombing: Low-Tech Terrorism in Prohibition-era New York
  Double X
The XX Factor
Sept. 15 2014 3:31 PM My Year As an Abortion Doula
  Slate Plus
Tv Club
Sept. 15 2014 11:38 AM The Slate Doctor Who Podcast: Episode 4  A spoiler-filled discussion of "Listen."
  Arts
Brow Beat
Sept. 16 2014 11:40 AM How to Put Things in Your Fridge
  Technology
Future Tense
Sept. 16 2014 7:36 AM The Inspiration Drought Why our science fiction needs new dreams.
  Health & Science
Bad Astronomy
Sept. 16 2014 7:30 AM A Galaxy of Tatooines
  Sports
Sports Nut
Sept. 15 2014 9:05 PM Giving Up on Goodell How the NFL lost the trust of its most loyal reporters.